Why Are Savings Rates So Low? The Core Reasons
Understand the multifaceted reasons behind current low savings rates and their impact on your money.
Understand the multifaceted reasons behind current low savings rates and their impact on your money.
Understanding why savings rates are low involves a complex interplay of economic forces. Grasping these dynamics is important because savings rates directly affect the growth of deposited funds and financial well-being. These rates are not arbitrary; they are influenced by decisions made by institutions and broader economic conditions. Many factors contribute to this low-interest-rate environment, impacting individual savers.
The central bank of the United States, the Federal Reserve, plays a significant role in determining interest rates through its monetary policy actions. Congress has given the Federal Reserve a dual mandate: to promote maximum employment and stable prices, along with moderate long-term interest rates. To achieve these objectives, the Federal Reserve influences the federal funds rate, which is the target rate at which banks lend reserves to each other overnight.
When the Federal Reserve adjusts this target rate, it creates a ripple effect throughout the financial system. If the Federal Reserve lowers the federal funds rate, it becomes cheaper for banks to borrow from each other, influencing the rates they offer on loans and deposits. Banks often adjust their deposit rates, including those for savings accounts, in response to these changes. This means that when the Federal Reserve lowers its benchmark rate, banks tend to reduce the interest they pay on savings.
Another tool the Federal Reserve employs is quantitative easing (QE), which involves buying government bonds and other financial assets from the open market. This action injects liquidity into the banking system, increasing the money supply and putting downward pressure on interest rates, especially longer-term rates. By making borrowing cheaper, QE aims to encourage investment and spending. The intent is to stimulate economic activity by making credit more accessible and affordable for businesses and consumers alike.
Broader macroeconomic conditions significantly shape the interest rate environment, often influencing the central bank’s policy decisions. One such condition is the level of inflation. When inflation is low and stable, there is less pressure on banks to offer high interest rates on savings accounts to compensate depositors for the erosion of their money’s purchasing power. A central bank targets a specific inflation rate, believing that stable prices foster economic health. If inflation remains below this target, interest rates are likely to remain subdued.
Periods of sluggish economic growth or recession also contribute to low savings rates. During economic downturns, central banks often lower interest rates to stimulate borrowing and spending. The goal is to make money cheaper to access, encouraging businesses to invest and expand, and consumers to spend, thereby boosting overall economic activity. Conversely, lower interest rates discourage saving by reducing the returns on deposits, nudging individuals and businesses to use their funds rather than hoard them.
High unemployment can also prompt central banks to maintain lower interest rates. An inverse relationship often exists between interest rates and unemployment, where lower rates can spur economic growth and encourage businesses to hire more workers. When unemployment is elevated, the central bank may lower rates to create conditions favorable for job creation and economic recovery. These macroeconomic indicators directly inform the central bank’s strategy, influencing the prevailing low savings rates.
The global supply and demand for money also play a role in determining domestic savings rates. A phenomenon sometimes referred to as a “global savings glut” describes a situation where the worldwide supply of savings exceeds the demand for investment opportunities. This abundance of capital can depress interest rates globally. When there is more money available to lend than there are profitable ventures to invest in, the price of borrowing—the interest rate—naturally falls.
Conversely, low demand for loans from businesses and individuals within a country can also contribute to lower savings rates. If economic uncertainty or a lack of appealing investment opportunities discourages companies from borrowing to expand, banks have less incentive to attract deposits by offering higher interest rates. When loan demand is weak, their need for deposit funding diminishes, leading them to offer less competitive rates to savers.
International interest rate differentials and the mobility of capital across borders can influence domestic savings rates. If interest rates are significantly higher in other countries, capital may flow out of the United States seeking better returns. However, in a world with abundant global savings, capital flows can instead push rates down in recipient countries like the U.S. This dynamic interconnectedness means that domestic savings rates are not solely determined by internal factors but are also shaped by the broader global financial environment.