What Is Classical Unemployment and What Causes It?
Understand classical unemployment, an economic theory explaining joblessness when wages are held above market-clearing levels.
Understand classical unemployment, an economic theory explaining joblessness when wages are held above market-clearing levels.
Unemployment is a persistent economic concern, representing a situation where individuals actively seeking employment are unable to find work. Within economic theory, various forms of unemployment exist, each attributed to different underlying causes. Classical unemployment is a particular type that economic models identify as stemming from specific market conditions. This concept helps to explain why some individuals may remain jobless even when jobs are theoretically available.
Classical unemployment occurs when the real wage rate in the labor market is set above the level that would naturally clear the market. This scenario leads to a situation where the supply of labor exceeds the demand for labor, resulting in a surplus of available workers who cannot find employment. This type of unemployment is not due to a lack of available jobs but rather because employers are unwilling or unable to pay the prevailing wage for all those seeking work.
The primary mechanism leading to classical unemployment is wage rigidity, meaning that wages do not easily adjust downwards to their equilibrium level. This rigidity can arise from various institutional factors that prevent wages from falling even when there is an excess supply of labor. For instance, government-mandated minimum wage laws set a legal floor for hourly pay, which can prevent wages from dropping below a certain point, potentially pricing some workers out of the market. Similarly, collective bargaining agreements negotiated by labor unions can establish wage rates and benefits that exceed what a competitive market might otherwise dictate.
Other factors contributing to wage rigidity include long-term employment contracts, which lock in wage rates regardless of short-term market fluctuations, and efficiency wages, where employers pay above-market wages to boost worker productivity or reduce turnover. When these rigidities keep wages artificially high, businesses may reduce their hiring or even lay off workers to control costs, leading to unemployment. The result is a persistent gap between the number of people willing to work and the number of jobs available at the prevailing wage.
Classical economic theory posits that markets, including the labor market, tend towards equilibrium. In this framework, any unemployment is viewed as voluntary or temporary, as wages would naturally adjust downwards to clear the market if there were an excess supply of labor. Classical unemployment represents a deviation from this ideal state, occurring when external factors prevent this natural wage adjustment. These rigidities are seen as the root cause, preventing the labor market from reaching its efficient equilibrium.
Specific examples of such rigidities include the federal minimum wage, creating a binding floor below which wages cannot fall for many employees. This mandated wage can be higher than the equilibrium wage for certain less-skilled positions, leading businesses to hire fewer workers than they would at a lower, market-determined rate. Another significant factor is the influence of powerful labor unions, which negotiate collective bargaining agreements that often include wage rates and benefit packages above competitive market levels. These agreements make it costly for employers to reduce wages.
Government regulations extending beyond minimum wages can also contribute to wage rigidity. For example, prevailing wage laws, such as the Davis-Bacon Act, require contractors on federally funded construction projects to pay wages and fringe benefits at least equal to those prevailing in the local area for similar work. These regulations, while intended to protect workers, can effectively set a wage floor that limits the ability of wages to fall in response to an excess supply of labor.
Understanding classical unemployment is enhanced by differentiating it from other common types of unemployment, each driven by distinct economic forces. Classical unemployment, fundamentally, arises from real wages being held above the market-clearing level due to rigidities. This contrasts sharply with frictional unemployment, which is a temporary state experienced by individuals who are between jobs, searching for new opportunities, or transitioning into the workforce. The search process itself, which can take a few weeks to several months, is the primary cause of frictional unemployment.
Structural unemployment, another distinct category, occurs when there is a mismatch between the skills workers possess and the skills employers require, or when jobs are geographically unavailable. This type of unemployment is often a result of long-term economic shifts, such as technological advancements that render certain skills obsolete, or industry declines that eliminate specific types of jobs. For instance, a coal miner losing their job due to the decline of the coal industry and lacking the skills for emerging tech jobs represents structural unemployment, a problem not directly related to wage levels.
Cyclical unemployment is directly tied to the overall health of the economy and the business cycle. It arises during economic downturns or recessions when there is a decrease in aggregate demand for goods and services, leading businesses to reduce production and lay off workers. This form of unemployment is widespread and resolves as the economy recovers and demand increases. Unlike classical unemployment, cyclical unemployment is not primarily caused by rigid wages but by insufficient overall economic activity.
Finally, Keynesian unemployment, sometimes linked to cyclical unemployment, specifically points to insufficient aggregate demand in the economy as the reason for joblessness. In the Keynesian view, even with flexible wages, a lack of overall spending can prevent the economy from achieving full employment. This perspective suggests that unemployment can persist not just due to wage rigidity, but also because there isn’t enough demand for goods and services to warrant full employment, distinguishing it from classical unemployment’s sole focus on wage levels.